24.3 Using Money to Buy Other Monies: Exchange Rates
Learning Objectives
After you have read this section, you should be able to answer the following questions:
- What is the difference between the nominal exchange rate and the real exchange rate?
- How is the law of one price related to the nominal exchange rate?
As we
all know, there are multiple currencies in the world. These are most
often associated with a single country: the yen in Japan, the yuan in
China, the peso in Mexico, and so on. Sometimes many countries will use
the same money, with the leading example being the use of the euro by
the member countries of the European Union (http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/euro/index_en.htm).
Sometimes multiple currencies are in use in a single place: when you
land at a major European airport, such as Frankfurt, Germany, or
Amsterdam, the Netherlands, you will see that you can buy a cup of
coffee at the airport using many different currencies. Likewise, the US
dollar is freely accepted in some countries in addition to the local
currency, British pounds formerly were freely accepted in Ireland, and
so on.
If you
happened to find your $100 right before going on a trip to another
country, you might decide to use it to buy the money of that country.
For example, if you were about to take a trip to Canada, you could take
the bill into a bank or a foreign exchange merchant and exchange it for
Canadian dollars. If you want to buy goods and services in Canada, you
need Canadian dollars because they are the medium of exchange in that
country.
When you
make such an exchange, you buy the local currency using your home
currency. If you travel from the United States to Europe, you buy euros
using dollars. The price you pay is the dollar price of the euro:
the amount in dollars you must pay to obtain 1 euro. This is completely
analogous to using a dollar to buy a bottle of soda, when you pay the
dollar price of soda.
In
practice, it is often unnecessary to carry out a physical exchange of
notes and coins. In most countries, you can go to an automated teller
machine (ATM) and withdraw local currency directly. Your bank deducts
the equivalent sum in your home currency from your bank account. You are
still carrying out an exchange, of course, but it is hidden from view,
and you will see it only when you look at your next statement. The same
is true if you make a purchase using a credit card.
Just as a
US resident traveling to Europe wishes to buy euros with dollars, a
visitor to the United States from, say, Holland will need to buy dollars
with euros. The price she pays is the euro price of the dollar: the
number of euros needed to obtain $1. The price of one currency in terms
of another is called an exchange rateThe price of one currency in terms of another..
If we
think of two currencies—euros and dollars, for example—then there are
two exchange rates to keep in mind: the price of euros in dollars and
the price of dollars in euros. (You might suspect, correctly, that these
two prices are linked; we return to this shortly.) In a world of 3
currencies, each has a price in terms of the other two currencies, so
there are 6 (= 3 × 2) different prices. And in a world of 100
currencies, then for each one, there are 99 prices for the other
currencies. So there are 100 × 99 = 9,900 prices to quote! A Zambian
traveling to Armenia wants to know about the kwacha price of drams, a
Malaysian traveling to Oman is interested in the ringgit price of rials,
and so on.
Foreign Exchange Markets
Imagine
a series of three visitors traveling from the United States to Europe.
First, we have someone arriving on vacation. Chances are that she will
want to exchange dollars for euros to have money to spend on hotels,
meals, and so on. She also buys souvenirs in Europe—goods that she
imports back to the United States. Our second visitor spends a lot of
time in Europe for work purposes. He might open a bank account in, say,
Germany. If he wanted, he could use this bank account to keep some of
his wealth in Europe. He would buy euros with his dollars, deposit these
euros in the bank to earn interest, and then—at some point in the
future—he would take his money out of the bank in Germany and exchange
the euros for dollars. (Later, we will consider how you can decide if
this is a good investment strategy. For now, our point is that this type
of financial investment is another source of demand for euros.) Our
third visitor to Europe is a professional wine buyer who wants to
purchase wine to sell in a US restaurant. She travels to the
wine-growing regions of Europe (France, Spain, Italy, Germany, Portugal,
etc.) and must exchange dollars for euros to pay for her purchases.
Our
three visitors represent a microcosm of the transactions that take
place in the foreign exchange market every day. Households and firms buy
euros to pay for their imports of goods and services (souvenirs, wine,
etc.). Many different goods and services are produced in Europe and sold
in the United States. Some are imported by retailers, others by
specialist import-export firms, and still others by individuals, but in
all cases there is an associated purchase of euros using dollars.
The
demand for euros also arises from financial investment by households,
firms, and financial institutions. For example, a wealthy private
investor in the United States may purchase stock issued by a company in
Europe. To buy that stock, the US investor sells dollars and buys euros.
In practice, such transactions are typically carried out by financial
institutions that undertake trades on behalf of households and firms.
Most
exchanges of dollars for euros do not actually entail someone traveling
to Europe. Think about the foreign currency needs of a large
multinational firm that produces goods and services in Europe but sells
its output in the United States. The company naturally needs euros to
pay workers and suppliers in Europe. Since it sells goods and thus earns
revenues in dollars, the company must convert from dollars to euros
very frequently. But you will not see the company’s chief financial
officer in an airport line to exchange money. Instead, such currency
operations are conducted through financial institutions, such as
commercial banks.
Because
of all these transactions, there are very active and sophisticated
markets in which currencies are traded. We can represent these markets
using the familiar supply-and-demand framework. Figure 24.4 "The Market for Euros"
shows a picture of the market where euros are bought and sold. Buyers
from the United States buy euros with dollars, and European traders sell
euros in exchange for dollars. The supply and demand
curves refer to the object being traded—euros. Thus the quantity of
euros is shown on the horizontal axis. The price on the vertical axis is
in dollars.
This
market is just like any other you encounter. The demand curve is
downward sloping: as the price of euros increases, the quantity of euros
demanded decreases. This is the law of demandPeople consume more of a good when its price decreases and less of a good when its price increases.
at work. As the price of euros increases, people in the United States
will find that goods and services produced in Europe are more expensive.
For example, suppose that 1 euro costs $1, and a Mercedes automobile
costs EUR 50,000.
Then its cost in dollars is $50,000. Now imagine that euros become more
expensive, so that EUR 1 now costs $2. You now need $100,000 to buy the
same Mercedes in Europe. So an increase in the price of euros means
that Americans choose to buy fewer goods and services produced in
Europe. Exactly the same logic tells us that an increase in the price of
the euro makes European assets look less attractive to investors. A
German government bond, a piece of real estate in Slovenia, or a share
in a Portuguese firm might look like good buys when the euro costs $1
yet seem like a bad idea if each euro costs $2.
The
supply curve also has a familiar upward slope. As the price of euros
increases, more people in Europe sell their euros in exchange for
dollars. They do so because with the higher dollar price of euros, they
can obtain more dollars for every euro they sell. This means that they
can buy more US goods and services or dollar-denominated financial
assets.
The price where supply equals demand is the equilibrium
exchange rate. (The market also shows us the equilibrium number of
euros traded, but here we are more interested in the price of the euro.)
Toolkit: Section 31.9 "Supply and Demand"
The foreign
exchange market is an example of a market that we can analyze using the
tool of supply and demand. You can review the supply-and-demand
framework and the meaning of equilibrium in the toolkit.
Arbitrage with Two Currencies
So
far, we have talked about buying foreign currencies to purchase either
assets or goods and services. Another reason to buy foreign currencies
is in the hope that you could make money by trading them. Let us think
about how you might try to make money in the foreign exchange market.
You might start with some dollars and exchange them for euros. Then you
could take those euros and exchange them for dollars again. Is it
possible that, by doing this, you could end up with more money than you
started with? Could you buy euros cheaply and then sell them at a high
price, thus making a profit?
Begin
by supposing that dollars and euros are only two currencies in the
world, and there are only two economies: the United States and Europe (a
shorthand for “those European countries that use the euro”). Imagine
that there are two separate markets: in the euro market, the price of 1
euro is $2; in the dollar market, the price of one dollar is EUR 1. With
these two prices, there is money to be made by buying and selling
currencies. Start with 1 euro. Sell that euro in the market for euros
and obtain $2. Use those dollars to buy euros in the market for euros
and obtain 2 euros. Now we are talking business: you started with 1
euro, made some trades, and ended up with 2 euros.
There
is, of course, a catch. The prices that we just suggested would not be
consistent with equilibrium in the foreign exchange markets. As we have
just seen, there is a simple recipe for making unlimited profit at these
prices, not only for you but also for everyone else in the market. What
would happen? Everyone would try to capitalize on the same opportunity
that you saw. Those with euros would want either to sell them in the
euro market—because euros are valuable—or to use them to buy dollars in
the dollar market—because dollars are cheap. Those with dollars,
however, would not want to buy expensive euros in the euro market, and
they would not want to sell them in the dollar market. Hence, in the
euro market, the supply of euros would shift rightward, and the demand
for euros would shift leftward. The forces of supply and demand would
make the dollar price of euros decrease. In the dollar market, the
supply of dollars would shift leftward, and the demand for dollars would
shift rightward, causing the euro price of dollars to increase.
The
mechanism we just described is arbitrage at work again. The arbitrage
possibility between the dollar market for euros and the euro market for
dollars disappears when the following equation is satisfied:
price of euro in dollars × price in dollar in euros = 1.
When
this condition holds, there is no way to buy and sell currencies in the
different markets and make a profit. As an example, suppose that EUR 1
costs $2 and $1 costs EUR 0.5. These prices satisfy the equation because
2 × 0.5 = 1. Imagine you start with $1. If you use it in the dollar
market for euros to buy euros, then you will have EUR 0.50. If you then
use these in the euro market for dollars to buy dollars, you will get $2
for each euro you supply to the market. Since you have half of a euro,
you will end up with $1, which is what you started with. There is no
arbitrage opportunity.
By
now you have probably realized that there is a close connection between
the market for euros and the market for dollars (where dollars are
bought and sold using euros). Whenever someone buys euros, they are
selling dollars, and whenever someone sells euros, they are buying
dollars. In our two-country, two-currency world, the market for euros
and the market for dollars are exactly the same market, just looked at
from two different angles.
We illustrate this in Figure 24.5 "The Market for Euros and the Market for Dollars". In part (a) of Figure 24.5 "The Market for Euros and the Market for Dollars", we show the market where euros are bought and sold, and in part (b) of Figure 24.5 "The Market for Euros and the Market for Dollars"
the market where dollars are bought and sold. The supply curve for
dollars is just the demand curve for euros, and the demand curve for
dollars is the same as the supply curve for euros. For example, suppose 1
euro costs $2. From part (a), we see that, at this price, people would
supply EUR 3,200. In other words, there are individuals who are willing
to exchange EUR 3,200 for $6,400. If we think about this from the
perspective of the market for dollars, these people would demand $6,400
in the market when $1 costs EUR 0.50—and, indeed, we see that this is a
point on the demand curve in part (b). The market is in equilibrium when
EUR 1.00 costs $1.25, or equivalently when $1 costs EUR 0.80. At this
exchange rate, holders of dollars are willing to give up $2,500, and
holders of euros are willing to give up EUR 2,000.
Arbitrage with Many Currencies
We live in a world with many different currencies, not just two. Figure 24.6 "Exchange Rates" shows some exchange rates from http://www.oanda.com,
a site that provides current and historical data on exchange rates and
that is also an online market where you can trade currencies. So, on
March 11, 2007, just after midnight, the price of a euro in dollars was
1.3115. At the same time, the price of a dollar in British pounds was
0.5176.
If you look at the table on the left side of Figure 24.6 "Exchange Rates",
you see that it provides both the dollar price of the euro and the euro
price of the dollar (and similarly for the other currency pairs).
Tables such as this one have already built in the arbitrage condition,
so you cannot keep buying and selling the same currency in exchange for
dollars and make money.
When
there are multiple currencies, we can imagine more complicated trading
strategies. As an example, consider the following string of
transactions.
- Take a dollar and use it to buy euros.
- Take the euros and buy Japanese yen.
- Take the yen and buy dollars.
If you
end up with more than $1, then there are profits to be made buying and
selling currencies in the manner outlined here. Can you make a profit
this way? The answer, once again, is no. If you could, then the markets
for foreign currency would not be in equilibrium: everyone would buy
euros with dollars, sell them for yen, and then sell the yen for
dollars. Once again, exchange rates would rapidly adjust to remove the
arbitrage opportunity.
To verify this, let us go through this series of transactions using Figure 24.6 "Exchange Rates".
One dollar will buy you EUR 0.7625. Now take these and use them to buy
yen. You will get 0.7625 × 155.1910 = JPY 118.3331. Now, use these yen
to buy dollars, and you will get 118.3331 × 0.00845 = $0.9999. You start
with $1; you end with $1 (give or take a rounding error).
These
calculations assume that there are no costs to trading foreign
currencies. In practice, there are costs involved in these exchanges. A
traveler arriving at an airport in need of local currency does not see
rates posted as in the left-hand table in Figure 24.6 "Exchange Rates".
Instead, they see something that looks like the right-hand table, where
rates are posted in two columns: bid (buying) and offer (selling). The
bid is a statement of how much the currency seller is willing to pay in
local currency for the listed currency. The offer column is the price in
local currency at which the seller is willing to sell to you.
Naturally, the offer price is bigger than the bid: the seller buys
currencies at a low price and sells them at a high price. The difference
between the bid and offer prices is called the spread.
The existence of the spread means that if you try to buy and sell
currencies with the dealer, you will actually lose money. At the same
time, the spread creates a profit margin for the dealer and thus pays
for the service that the dealer provides.
Arbitrage with Goods and Currencies
We
have talked about arbitrage with goods and arbitrage with foreign
currencies. We can also put the two together to study the prices of
goods that are traded across international borders. Arbitrage of goods
from one country to another is a bit more complicated because it
involves buying and selling currencies as well as goods. To see how this
works, imagine you are going on a trip to Europe. You are allowed two
suitcases filled with belongings free of charge on the airplane. What
about filling a suitcase full of new blue jeans, transporting them to
Europe, and then selling them there? Could you make money that way?
Suppose
that the dollar price of 1 euro is $1.50. Further, suppose that the
price of a pair of blue jeans is $70.00 in the United States and EUR
50.00 in Paris. Consider the following sequence of actions.
- Take $70 out of your pocket and buy a pair of blue jeans.
- Travel with these blue jeans to Paris.
- Sell the jeans for euros.
- Buy dollars with your euros.
The
question is whether you can make money in this way. The answer is given
by how many dollars you will have in your pocket at the end of these
steps. When you sell the jeans in Paris, you will have EUR 50.00. If the
dollar price of euros is $1.50, then by selling the jeans in Paris you
will get 50 × $1.50 = $75. This is a profit of $5 for each pair of
jeans—you are in business.
Once
again, the opportunity for arbitrage suggests that this situation is
unlikely to persist. Entrepreneurs will buy jeans in the United States,
take them to Paris, and sell them there. Market forces in three
different markets will work to eliminate the profit. First, the activity
of arbitrageurs will increase the demand for jeans in the United
States, causing the US price of jeans to increase. Second, the increased
supply of jeans in Paris will cause the price there to decrease. And
third, there will be an increased supply of euros in the foreign
exchange market, which will cause the euro to depreciate. This is shown
in Figure 24.7 "International Arbitrage Restores the Law of One Price".
These
price changes continue until there are no profits to be made by
arbitrage. Exactly how much of the adjustment will take place in each
market depends on the slopes of the supply and demand curves. In Figure 24.7 "International Arbitrage Restores the Law of One Price",
we have drawn the new equilibrium as follows: blue jeans cost EUR 49 in
Europe and $71.05 in the United States; and the exchange rate is $1.45
per euro. At these prices,
price of blue jeans in dollars = price of blue jeans in euros × price of euro in dollars,
and
there is no longer any possibility of arbitrage. This is another
illustration of the law of one price. If we were literally talking just
about arbitrage in blue jeans, most of the adjustment would take place
in the markets for blue jeans in the United States and Europe, and there
would be a negligible effect on the exchange rate. But if the same
kinds of arbitrage opportunities exist for lots of goods, then there
will be an impact on the exchange rate as well.
For tradable goodsGoods that can be easily and cheaply transported from one place to another, which means they can be easily arbitraged., the law of one price says that the
dollar price of good = euro price of good × dollar price of euro.
When
this condition holds, there are no arbitrage profits to be gained by
purchasing the good with dollars, selling it for euros, and then buying
dollars with euros. Likewise, if this condition holds, there are also no
arbitrage profits from purchasing the good with euros, selling it for
dollars, and then buying euros with dollars. In general, we expect that
such arbitrage will occur very quickly. There are no profits to be made
from arbitrage when the law of one price holds.
The Economist
has kept track of the price of a McDonald’s Big Mac in a number of
countries for many years, creating something they call the “the Big Mac
index.” Table 24.1 "The " contains some of their data. The last column of Table 24.1 "The "
gives the price of a Big Mac in each selected country in July 2011,
converted to US dollars at the current exchange rate. That is, the last
column is calculated by dividing the local currency price (the second
column) by the exchange rate (the third column). A Big Mac costs $4.07
in the United States but more than twice as much in Norway. China is a
real deal at only $1.89.
Table 24.1 The Economist’s Big Mac Index, July 2011
Country |
Local Currency Price of Big Mac |
Local Currency Price of a Dollar |
Price in US Dollars |
United States |
USD 4.07 |
1 |
4.07 |
Norway |
NOK 45 |
5.41 |
8.31 |
Euro Area |
EUR 3.44 |
0.70 |
4.93 |
Czech Republic |
CZK 69.3 |
17.0 |
4.07 |
China |
CNY 14.7 |
6.45 |
1.89 |
The
price differentials in this table violate the law of one price: there
is (apparently) profit to be made by buying Big Macs at a low price and
selling them at a high price. Applying the principle of arbitrage, we
should all be flying to China, buying Big Macs, traveling to Norway, and
selling them on the streets of Oslo. Of course, there are a few small
problems with this scheme, such as the following:
- It is expensive to fly back and forth between China and Norway.
- There is a limited capacity for transporting Big Macs on the airplane.
- The quality of the Big Mac might deteriorate while it is being transported.
- You might not be permitted to import meat products from China into Norway.
- You might have to pay taxes when you bring Big Macs into Norway.
- It might be tough to open a McDonald’s in Oslo.
This
long list easily explains the deviations from the law of one price for
Big Macs. Similar considerations explain why the law of one price might
not hold for other goods. The law also does not apply to services, such
as tattoos, since these cannot be imported and exported. The law of one
price is most applicable to goods that are homogeneous and easily traded
at low cost. Economists use the law of one price as a guide but
certainly do not expect it to hold for all products in all places.
Using the Law of One Price to Understand the Exchange Rate
There is another way to interpret the finding that Big Macs do not cost the same in each country. The Economist
uses this information to draw conclusions about the values of different
currencies and how these values are likely to change over time.
From
this perspective, the Big Mac is more expensive in Europe than in the
United States because dollars are cheap in Europe. Put differently, we
say that the dollar is undervaluedThe price of a currency is too low compared to the ratio of price levels in the two countries.
relative to the euro. If the price of a dollar in euros were 0.85
instead of 0.70, then a Big Mac would cost the same in the United States
and Europe. Completely equivalently, we can say that that the euro is overvaluedThe price of a currency is too high compared to the ratio of price levels in the two countries.
relative to the dollar. With this in mind, we might expect the
undervalued dollar to increase in value relative to the euro. That is,
we would expect the price of a dollar in euros to increase. Similarly,
we would conclude that the Norwegian kroner is overvalued relative to
the dollar, the Chinese yuan is undervalued, and the Czech Koruna is
neither overvalued nor undervalued.
To
see how this works more generally, look back at our arbitrage condition
for blue jeans. If we divide both sides by the price of blue jeans in
euros, we get
This
equation says that, according to the law of one price, the dollar price
of the euro should equal the dollar price of blue jeans divided by the
price of blue jeans in euros. This is exactly the kind of calculation
that underlies the Big Mac index, only with blue jeans instead of Big
Macs. Equivalently, the law of one price says that the
Suppose
we think about this equation applying (approximately) to all goods and
services. We can then get a better prediction of the exchange rate by
looking at a general price index in each country:
Because
of all the reasons why the law of one price does not literally hold,
economists certainly do not expect this equation to give an exact
prediction of the exchange rate. Nevertheless, it can provide a useful
indication of whether a currency is undervalued or overvalued.
A
currency is undervalued if, following this equation, its price is too
low compared to the ratio of price levels in the two countries. A
currency is overvalued if, following this equation, its price is too
high compared to the ratio of price levels in the two countries. As in
our discussion of the euro, if a currency is overvalued, then we would
expect its value to decrease over time. This is called a depreciationA decrease in the price of a currency. of the currency. Likewise, we would expect the price of an undervalued currency to increase over time. This is called an appreciationAn increase in the price of a currency. of the currency.
The
market forces behind these currency movements come from the buying and
selling of currencies for trading purposes. If the Chinese yuan is
undervalued, goods produced in China will be relatively cheap in US
dollars. The demand for Chinese exports will be high, and this will lead
to a large demand for the yuan. Eventually the dollar price of the yuan
will increase—that is, the yuan will appreciate, and the dollar will
depreciate.
Changes in the Exchange Rate
Even
though the law of one price does not literally hold for all goods and
services, it reminds us that the value of $1 in the United States is
linked to its value in the rest of the world. As a result, we expect
that price level changes are likely to lead to
changes in the exchange rate. We see this more clearly if we write our
previous equation in terms of growth rates. Using the formula for growth
rates, we find the following:
growth rate of price of dollar in euros = growth rate of price of European bundle of goods− growth rate of price of US bundle of goods.
If the bundle of goods in each country corresponds roughly to the goods in the Consumer Price Index (CPI)A price index that uses as the bundle of goods the typical purchases of households., then the growth rate of these prices corresponds to the inflation rateThe growth rate of the price index from one year to the next..
The growth rate of the exchange rate is just another term for the
percentage appreciation of the currency. Thus we get the following:
percentage appreciation of the dollar ≈ European inflation rate − US inflation rate.
So,
if the inflation rate in the United States is higher than it is in
Europe, we expect the euro price of the dollar to decrease. We expect
depreciation of the dollar if US inflation exceeds European inflation.
Inflation reduces the real value of money domestically; it will also
tend to reduce the value of money in terms of what it can purchase in
the rest of the world. This makes sense. If our currency is becoming
less valuable at home, then we should also expect it to become less
valuable in the rest of the world.
The Real Exchange Rate
The law of one price is connected to another measure of the exchange rate—the real exchange rateA measure of the price of goods and services in one country relative to another when prices are expressed in a common currency.. This exchange rate is a measure of the price of goods and services in one country relative to another when prices are expressed in a common currency. It is about exchanging goods, rather than money, across countries.
The real exchange rate between the United States and Europe is given as follows:
You
can think of the real exchange rate as the number of units of European
gross domestic product (GDP) you can get for one unit of US GDP.
For example, if the price level in the United States is $1,600, the
price level in Europe is EUR 400, and the price of dollars in euros is
EUR 0.5, then the real exchange rate is as follows:
One unit of US GDP will get you two units of European GDP.
The
real exchange rate is intimately linked to the law of one price. The
easiest way to see this is to suppose that we measure US real GDP and
European GDP in the same units: that is, suppose we use the same bundle
of goods in each case. We know that the law of one price should hold for
tradable goods—that is, goods for which arbitrage is possible and
practical. If every good that went into GDP were tradable, then the law
of one price would hold for every good, and the real exchange rate would
equal 1. If the real exchange rate was not 1, you could make arbitrage
profits by buying and selling “units of GDP.”
As
before, suppose the US price level is $1,600, the European price level
is EUR 400, and the nominal exchange rate (dollars per euro) is 0.5.
Imagine that US GDP and European GDP measure the same bundle of
(tradable) goods. Then you could take $800 and buy EUR 400. With these
euros, you could buy a basket of goods in Europe. You could sell this
basket in the United States for $1,600. The law of one price is
violated. We would expect the following:
- Prices in the United States would increase.
- Prices in Europe would decrease.
- The nominal exchange rate would depreciate (the dollar would become less valuable).
Because
arbitrage is not possible for all goods and services, we do not
expect—nor do we observe—the real exchange rate to be exactly one. But
this benchmark is still useful in understanding movements in the real
exchange rate.
The Real Exchange Rate in Action
The
real exchange rate matters because it is the price that is relevant for
import and export decisions. Suppose you are trying to decide between
buying a mobile phone manufactured in the United States and one
manufactured in Finland. If the dollar appreciates against the euro,
then the US phone retailer needs fewer dollars to purchase euros, so
Finnish phones will be cheaper in US stores. If prices decrease in
Finland, the imported phone again becomes relatively cheaper. If prices
increase in the United States, the US phone will be more expensive. In
other words, increasing prices in the United States, decreasing prices
in Finland, and appreciation of the dollar all make you more likely to
buy the imported phone rather than the domestically produced phone.
More
generally, anything that causes the real exchange rate to increase will
make imports look more attractive compared to goods produced in the
domestic economy. Examined from the point of view of Europe, the same
increase in the real exchange rate makes US goods look more expensive
relative to goods produced in Europe, so Europeans will be likely to
import fewer goods from the United States. An increase in the real
exchange rate therefore leads to an increase in US imports and a
decrease in US exports—that is, it leads to a decrease in net exportsExports minus imports..
The
real exchange rate can and does vary substantially over time. Argentina
in the 1990s provides a nice illustration of real exchange rates in
action. Argentina had a currency boardA
fixed exchange rate regime in which each unit of domestic currency is
backed by holding the foreign currency, valued at the fixed exchange
rate. during this period. Under a currency board, a
country maintains a fixed exchange rate by backing its currency
completely with another currency. Although Argentina did have its own
currency (the Argentine peso), each peso in circulation was backed by a
US dollar held by the Argentine central bank. You could at any time
exchange pesos for dollars at a nominal exchange rate of 1.
Figure 24.8 "The Real Exchange Rate in Argentina"
shows what happened to prices in Argentina and the United States over
this period. Look at 1992–95. Both countries had some inflation. But
prices were increasing faster in Argentina than in the United States.
The real exchange rate (Argentina–United States) is given by
because
the price of the peso in dollars was 1. Therefore the real exchange
rate appreciated as Argentine inflation outpaced US inflation.
The
appreciation of the real exchange rate meant that Argentine goods
became more expensive in other countries, so Argentine exports became
less competitive. (The problem was compounded by the fact that the US
dollar [and hence the peso] also appreciated against the currencies of
neighboring countries such as Brazil.) Without the currency board, it
would have been possible for the nominal exchange rate (price of the
peso in dollars) to decline, offsetting the effects of the inflation
rate. Instead, this appreciation of the real exchange rate ended up
causing substantial economic problems in Argentina in the 1990s. In the
second half of the decade, the real exchange rate began to depreciate
because the inflation rate in Argentina was lower than in the United
States. The appreciation at the start of the decade had been so large,
however, that the real exchange rate in 1999 was still higher than it
had been in 1992.
If
countries want to have a permanently fixed exchange rate, there is an
option that is more radical than a currency board. Countries can decide
to adopt a common currency, like the European countries that adopted the
euro. There are several reasons why countries might decide to take such
a course of action. The first advantage of a common currency is that it
enhances the role of money as a medium of exchange. There is no longer a
need to exchange one currency for another, making it easier to trade
goods and services across countries. People do not have to deal with the
inconveniences of exchanging currencies: individuals do not have to
exchange cash at airports, and firms do not need to manage multiple
currencies to conduct international business. In the jargon of
economics, a single currency removes transaction costs. These costs
might be individually small, but they can add up when you consider just
how many times households and firms needed to switch from one of the
euro area currencies to another.
One
way to picture this advantage is to imagine the reverse. Suppose, for
example, that each state in the United States decided to adopt its own
currency. Trade across state lines would become more complicated and
more costly. Even more starkly, imagine that your hometown had its own
currency, so you had to exchange money whenever you traveled anywhere
else.
A
second advantage of a single currency is that it makes business
planning easier. A firm in Belgium can write a contract with another
firm in Spain without having to worry about the implications of currency
appreciation or depreciation. Thus an argument for the move to a single
currency was that such a change was likely to encourage trade among
countries of the European Union. Again, imagine how much more
complicated business would be in the United States if each state had its
own freely floating currency.
Finally,
a common currency enhances capital flows. Just as it is easier for
businesses to trade goods and services, it is also easier for investors
to shift funds from country to country. With a common currency,
investors do not have to pay the transactions costs of converting
currencies, and they no longer face the uncertainty of exchange rate
changes. When capital flows more easily across borders, investment
activity is more productive, enhancing the growth of the countries
involved.
Key Takeaways
- The nominal exchange rate is the price of one currency in terms of
another. The real exchange rate compares the price of goods and services
in one country to the cost of these goods and services in another
country when all prices are in a common currency.
- From the law of one price, a tradable good in
one country should have the same price as that same good in another
country when the goods are priced in the same currency. This means that
the exchange rate is equal to the ratio of the prices expressed in the
two different currencies. Put differently, by the law of one price, the
real exchange rate between tradable goods should be 1.
Checking Your Understanding
- If the price of a euro was $2 and the price of a dollar was 1 EUR, how would you make a profit?
- If goulash sells for either 1,090 forint or 4.40
euro, what is the price of the forint in terms of the euro? Do the two
prices of cabbage quoted in Figure 24.3 "The Euro as a Unit of Account" yield a different euro price for the forint? Is there an arbitrage possibility here (or elsewhere on the menu)?